A while ago I
wrote about an
academic article I’d had published that suggested successive governments’
alcohol policies can usefully be labelled neoliberal. The reason this was worth saying, I
suggested, was that some policy commentators have talked about policy entering
a new phase since 2008, as confidence in market mechanisms and individual
rationality have faltered in light of the crash and recession and there’s been
an increasing emphasis on community-focused interventions through developments
such as Blue Labour, Red Toryism, and David Cameron’s idea of the Big Society.
The first step in this argument is to note that governments
have loosened regulation of the alcohol industry, particularly through the 2003
Licensing Act, but also well before that, from the 1980s on. Phil
Mellows has suggested that the Beer Orders can be seen as neoliberal, as
(however misguidedly) they sought to open up the market to greater levels of
competition.
But in itself this could just be liberalism. The same arguments about competition were
made in the nineteenth century in terms of the Beer Acts. What made these more recent developments neoliberalism,
I argued, was the peculiar way in which government was clearly panicked about
alcohol and worried about particular types of drinking. Alcohol strategies were published by
successive governments, and millions of pounds were spent on advertising
campaigns to persuade the public to Know
Your Limits, know your Units,
and behave on a night out in a sober
fashion.
This can be seen as neoliberal because it isn’t based on a
belief that a
person’s own way of laying out their life is by definition the best for them. Rather, the government thinks it knows
best, and it’s unhappy about the results produced when British people (who are
born to binge?) are invited
to binge.
For most of the twentieth century, the response by
government to such a feeling of unhappiness would have been to change the
environment that seemed to produce that outcomes – hence the Central Control
Board (CCB) and the retention of relatively restrictive licensing laws even
after the end of the First World War, more or less through to the 21st
century. It’s not really important what
this period is called (some would question the term ‘expansive liberalism’
which a few social policy academics use), but it’s clearly quite different to
the approach to alcohol policy taken by successive governments in the past 30
years. In this more recent approach, the
market is taken as given, and it’s the individual drinkers who are told to
change.
It’s possible to say that the 20th century was
unusual in terms of the restrictions put on the alcohol trade, but I’d argue
that such a position is misleading.
Retail of alcohol has been licensed for centuries, and it was only for
rare periods of history that numbers of pubs, inns, taverns, alehouses and so
forth were determined solely by market forces.
In fact, schemes comparable to the CCB were in operation in a range of
towns at various points in the early modern period, on the basis that directly
controlling the numbers of licences wasn’t enough; the profit motive should
also be removed from licensees’ day-to-day operations.*
So far, so neoliberal.
And yet, writing recently about the particular context for England’s
apparently neoliberal alcohol policy (it unsurprisingly involves the
carnivalesque, in case you were wondering), I was reminded of James Nicholls’ work on liberalism and
alcohol policy, and his
broader work on the history of alcohol policy, which notes how many of the
same arguments and dynamics crop up again and again – if in slightly different
forms. This reminded me that there isn’t
a single ‘liberal’ position in relation to this unusual substance,
alcohol. TH Green was a liberal who
advocated prohibition, while this was anathema to JS Mill. Perhaps we could see the 20th
century as a form of watered down (or beered up?) TH Green style liberalism,
and the current period as Millian? (This
post owes much to James Nicholls.)
The distinction between the period from 1915 to the 1980s
and the time since then is, in my account, that both had clear view of
how people should drink, and accepted the free(ish) market wouldn’t
produce these, but the solutions to this perceived problem were different. The first sought to change the environment in
which people made their drinking decisions; the second sought to change the
people.
The latter might sound distant from an idea of pure,
classical liberalism that values individual judgement, but is in fact remarkably
similar to the views of Adam Smith or Mill.
They accepted that there were higher pleasures, or that the desire for
drunkenness was a bad thing – but argued that education, exposure to
alternative pastimes and changes in working conditions would be better
solutions than limiting
the numbers of alehouses or prohibiting the sale of alcohol altogether.
Hasn’t that been the hope of Labour and Coalition
policies? Drop MUP but keep funding Units,
Would You and Change for Life to show people the ‘better’ life they could have?
Maybe this neoliberalism isn’t so new after all.
No comments:
Post a Comment